November IEA global production

Average monthly oil production from various estimates. Click to enlarge. Believed to be all liquids. Graph is not zero-scaled. Source: IEA, and EIA. The IEA raw line is what they initially state each month. The IEA corrected line is calculated from the month-on-month production change quoted the following month.

There's about five posts I want to write tonight, and only time to do one of them. I picked an analysis arising from the debate with Freddy Hutter today about my Thanksgiving day graph of Oil and Gas Journal monthly production.

The graph above shows three estimates of average monthly global production since the beginning of 2002 (ie the doldrums after the tech crash in the world economy). The dark green line is the EIA estimate, which only goes through September 2005. The thin blue line is what the IEA says about monthly production in each of their monthly reports (which typically come about 10 days after the end of the month). However, the following month, they report a change from the prior month which generally implies a significant recalculation of the prior month (occasionally they explicitly acknowledge it, but not usually). Anyway, that recalculated line is the plum colored one, and is presumably their more reliable estimate.

The EIA says "Oil Supply includes crude oil, natural gas plant liquids, other liquids, and refinery processing gain." They also mention that the US number includes ethanol added to gasoline. I couldn't find a description of exactly what the IEA includes.

As Freddy notes, the November estimate is the IEA's highest ever raw estimate. Lately, they have tended to revise downwards, so perhaps this one will go down too. However, I caution that over the whole period shown, the average IEA revision is -54kbd, which is 1.35 standard deviations below zero (not statistically significant), so one has to argue that they tended to revise up in 2002, and revise down in 2004-2005. The IEA number is on average 125kbpd below the EIA, but with a standard deviation of 500kbd, and a standard error of 74kbpd. Thus the average difference between the two agencies is only 1.7 standard errors from zero and is not statistically significant either (over this time period).

Overall, it still looks to me like there was a structural break last summer. Whether we are very close to peak, or we will crawl up some more is hard to tell, but the sharp increases of 2002-2004 definitely seemed to stop in the middle of last year. Given my best current understanding of decline rates in current production, and the fact that OPEC is threatening to cut output, it's hard for me to see massive increases in the near term. At least now I've done the hard work of extracting the IEA data and can easily include future months in this graph. We await the December report with eager interest...

Thanks for digging out the facts.
Your Thanksgiving graph is now my desktop wallpaper. More exactly, the unasimple
"enhanced" graph.
Anybody knows where to find info to update that graph?

Barbara
(no english mothertongue)

Let's wait for the data from 2006 to see if the oil production will mantain a plateau or if the oil production will go down....

For me is clear that Peak Oil is ON US NOW. We are lucky to see it at this site, I imagine how many years we will wait before the media start to say it. I am sure we will see a lot of Saud's government official lies going to the first pages saing that there is no peak Oil and that Santa Claus will give us all oil we need if we stay good to the Saud...

Happy Peakxmas!

Thanks again Stuart and the rest of TOD group for digging out all the numbers and presenting them in a simplified form.  I read many of the comments in the Freddy Hutter thread.  This is a very complicated data set for those of us who don't live and breath the oil business.

We do seem to be at a point where "Past performance is not a guarantee of future performance" in oil production.  Lots of predictions on production seem to be based on trend lines from 2-3 years ago that visually don't appear to be met late in 2005.  This means reaching those far off production goals requires even greater % increases over current supply.  Not likely in my opinion.

Lastly, lumping ethanol into petroleum liquids seems to be a desperate attempt to pad the numbers.  Does this mean that if we stay at a plateau of production, but replace 25% of the petroleum liquids with ethanol and biodiesel over the next decade that we have no petroleum production issues?  That peak oil doesn't exist?  This just seems like a desperate attempt to minimize the reality of field depletion as the driver for production declines or lack of increase.

The US gasoline consumption is 9.5 million barrels / day, 9.5 * 365 * 42 = about 145 billion gallons annually. The US annual corn crop harvest is 10 billion bushels. 10 * 2.5 = 25 billion gallons of ethanol. Ethanol yield is about 2.5 gallons per bushel. 25 / 145 = about 17% If we used the entire annual corn crop to produce ethanol, 10% could be used for gasohol while the other 7% would be consumed by increased demand before the new ethanol plants came on line.
In addition to corn I have been looking at some numbers on soybeans and potatoes.
The US harvests about 2.5 billion bushels of soybeans annually, and about 23 million tons of potatoes. Potatoes yield about 25-30 gallons of ethanol/ton or 688 million gallons of ethanol about .5% of our gas consumption.
There has been much talk about bio-diesel from soybeans. The only numbers I can find are that soybeans yield about 9.5 to 10 pounds of oil/bushel. How much bio-diesel will 10 pounds of soybean oil yield?? 1.5 Gallons max, that would make 3.75 billion gallons of bio-diesel. Our annual distillate consumption is 4.5*365*42=69 billion gallons. Soybean bio-diesel would only supply 5.4% of our distillate needs. 3.75/69=.0543.
I hope this can put in perspective our alternate liquid fuels problem. There is no way the USA can ever supply even 10% our liquid fuel with ethanol & biodiesel.
I am growing increasingly skeptical about biofuels as a solution.  In addition to the issues you bring up, it appears that there are serious environmental impacts due to soil depletion and possible nutrient removal (especially if we try to use the leftover biomass so as to preserve the edible portions of the plant), as well as the incentive for deforestation.  And there is the EROEI issue.

Other than massive nuclear and wind and solar, I don't see what the energy source is going to be once oil goes into serious decline, and that does not address the transportation fuel issue unless we replace our transportation infrastructure.  And we have not started yet.  Using less energy is the only solution.  If we have 20 years, maybe we can do it, but if the top of that curve keeps tipping over....

But don't worry, because I heard on the radio this morning that the Saudis have been pumping like mad, and have produced so much oil that they expect to throttle back early next year, and the gas prices will go down further (back up to $2.29 this morning), and the economy will take off.  But there's no need to worry about inflation in spite of all the jobs that will be created. The FCC really needs to work on blocking those broadcasts from other dimensions....

Twilight,

I'm with you on biofuels.  Love the concept.  Just can't get the numbers to add.  It's a last resort idea and requires huge reduction in total fuel consumption.

Twilight:  Agreed, but then there is another problem with bio-diesel. Currently an average to excellent soybean yield is about 50 bushels/acre. At $6.00 a bushel that is a $300 annual/acre crop, However at best it will yield about 75 gallons of oil and 60 gallons of bio-diesel. That means with zero capitol and processing expense, the bio-diesel has a crop cost alone of $5.00 per gallon.
I understand that Minnesota has enacted a 2% bio-diesel law that requires nearly all diesel fuel to be blended with 2% bio-diesel. Now I don't know how much nearly is, but here is a web-site to explain it further.
http://www.mda.state.mn.us/biodiesel/b2/default.htm
Here is a web-site of oil yield for oil-bearing crops.
http://journeytoforever.org/biodiesel_yield.html#ascend
Just thought I'd note this development for the group:

Vermont Gets Hydrogen Car Grant
Vermont will take part in a federally-funded project to demonstrate the practicality of hydrogen-powered cars.

The technology is expensive, but Vermonters involved in the project say there's good reason to move ahead with it.

"There's a lot of science behind this," Rep. Bernie Sanders, I-Vermont, told reporters at a press conference where he brought representatives of non-profit groups and entrepreneurs involved in the project.

Sanders announced a nearly one-million dollar grant from the Dept. of Energy for one of several demonstration projects around the country aimed at moving the nation off fossil fuels. Already, the first hydrogen fueling station in New England is under construction near the Burlington Electric Department headquarters on Pine St. It will take power from a nearby B.E.D.-owned wind turbine, taking the hydrogen out of water and using the gas to power a car.

So we're moving from the theoretical to the practical, at least as a demonstration. Here's the rest.

Don't use the words "practical" and "hydrogen" in the same sentence until you have calculated the energy throughput.

You get about twice as much energy from wind to wheels using batteries compared to using hydrogen.

OK but I did say as a "demonstration."

If what you say is true, then we are heading down a dead end. Why are smart people throwing time and money away on hydrogen if batteries are the answer? Is it that they just don't know? Do you have a link to a source that proves what you say? I'd like to know because then I'll pass it along to the folks downtown who are building this project.

Why are smart people throwing time and money away on hydrogen if batteries are the answer? Is it that they just don't know?
It's because hydrogen is relatively good for carrying energy from fossil fuels, and the fossil-fuel interests have made certain that the research money favors their products.  The people who want to do development have to go where the money is.
Do you have a link to a source that proves what you say?
There are dozens (the calculations are simple), but you might want to start with Future  Pundit's roundup before you take my word for it.
Great web site you have there, thanks. Very thorough. Something else for me to spend hours poring over instead of working, which is what I should be doing.

I try to retain some sense of optimism about all of this, that either by building an abundance of new nuclear power plants we'll be able to have enough electricity AND stay warm; that Stirling engine solar farms will deliver the solar promise without the drawbacks of traditional PV; that hydrogen will replace kerosene to keep our air fleet flying; that electric cars will keep us all in motion... but when you think of the folly, the stupidity, the blindness, the corruption, the deceit and the wishful thinking that is going on everywhere, I can't help but think, We Are So Totally Screwed. Anyway, it's Christmas Eve, so Merry Christmas and Happy Holidays to you. I've got to get into my Jeep and go to the bank 15 miles from here to deposit a check so I can buy some plastic crap for the neighbors' children while looking at Christmas lights which I used to enjoy which I now know are using up coal that we're all going to need in the future and wondering all the while just how much my house is going to drop in value when fuel becomes so expensive that people abandon the countryside and flock to the cities to stay warm and earn a living under futuristic Dickensian conditions from which we'll never escape. Merry Christmas!

I am growing increasingly skeptical about biofuels as a solution.
And rightly so, but check out my calculations here and tell me if I've got something wrong.
Biofuels are not a solution to current consumption patterns. We can, however, produce enough biofuels to operate those industries that depend upon liquid hydrocarbon fuels such as mining. Commuter transportation has to move to electric. Whether that's electric cars, light rail, or whatever matters less than just moving to electric and being done with it. Overland cargo transport needs to move to a combination of waterways again (rivers and canals) and electric trains.

Even the use of sustainable cellulose residue (instead of food crops) can only achieve 14.5 billion gallons (345 million barrels) of ethanol annually. The clear message here is that liquid fuels consumption has to go down. The clearest way to achieve that is migrating to electric transportation which can be supported by solar, wind, nuclear, and clean coal electric generating processes.

We can achieve a sustainable yet advanced technological civilization with what we know today. No, it won't look like what we have today but it's still better than the alternative of collapse. The only question is whether we will do so or not?

I agree with your assessment completely.  

However what if sugar cane, coconut and date palms WORLD WIDE gets shunted into fuels.  This has already started in Indonesia and Brazil.  We already import gasoline and ethanol and we have a big appetite for transportation fuels.  I agree again with you that this still won't replace a very large percentage of petroleum.  But it could mask declines for awhile in the reports.

DP

Do you have numbers for Canola or Mustard seed?
Soy beans is the worst example to give and in my mind, are a net-energy loss or close to it.
The numbers that I have seen (from coastal areas) say both canola and mustard yield close to 100 gallons per acre.  And they also are a great rotation crop for wheat to replenish the soil, so farmers must grow these (or something else) anyway.

There is no way the USA can ever supply even 10% our liquid fuel with ethanol & biodiesel.

This is a very bold statement.  We haven't even begun to tap ethanol from wood yet and it is an energy gain and can be processed from existing paper mills, but a cheaper method must be worked out.  The average car also get 21 MPG, if this number ever got to 42 (and it will with price) 10% would be more like 6-7% currently.

Biodiesel: Perhaps you could read a post from pomona96 on jumping on the tech bandwagon from Sun Dec 4 concerning wood product bio-diesel.
Here is a web-site of oil yield for oil-bearing crops.
http://journeytoforever.org/biodiesel_yield.html#ascend
Well now you see my issue.  Canola and Mustard seed yield almost 3 times the amount of oil that soy beans put out.  Yet you always use the soybean example.  Just showing we can both come to a conclusion and use the "data" to back up our claims.
Really though it's all speculation, countries that currently use ethanol/biodiesel to power a large % of their combustion, will start to have problems if you are right.  OTOH they will suceed and keep showing economic growth if I am right.
Brazil will be the first test case, 40% of their transportation fuel comes from ethanol.  Results will come foward shortly.  Same with France and Germany who use close to 5% biodiesel.  (and they don't use soy)
I'm sure Pomona has data and I can point to many other engineers with data as well.
Just like peak oil, no one really knows when and everyone can use data to claim they know.  But claiming the US will never have ethanol/biodiesel power 10% of our transportation, is a rather bold call when other countries have surpassed or are closing in on that number.
I agree about the ethanol inclusion.  I truly appreciate Stuart's attempts to provide apples-to-apples comparisons, which it would appear is not easy to do.  It is very frustrating to me as it looks like all the data is seriously compromised in some way or another.  If one were trying to determine how much fuel of all kinds we are using, then adding in ethanol is ok, but if we are trying to determine world oil production, then what is it doing there?  Why not include toilet bowl cleaner?  How about milk products?
As far as I can tell, they are only including the ethanol that actually goes in gasoline.  So it seems legitimate as far as that goes (it is part of "all liquids used like oil".  Of course, whether the government should be subsidizing them to put it in gasoline is another question.
Exactly!

Could you post the raw data or a URL to the raw data?

Thanks.

Stuart gives this link where data is available in spreadsheet format:
http://www.eia.doe.gov/emeu/ipsr/supply.html

You can read the monthly reports in PDF format from here:
http://omrpublic.iea.org/archiveresults.asp?formsection=supply&formdate=%25&Submit=Submit

whose parent site (public data from EIA) is:
http://omrpublic.iea.org/

Many thanks for doing that, Stuart, excellent job and sound analysis IMO. I found a more detailed definition of supply as used by EIA here:
http://omrpublic.iea.org/currentissues/sup.pdf   (page 51)

Definition of Supply
In order to achieve a mass balance in the world oil supply and demand table (Table 1), supply includes not only crude oil and NGLs, but also various types of heavy oil-like hydrocarbons and natural gas-based, coal-based and renewable-based sources which are used as oil product equivalents and are included in our definition of demand. These non-conventional oils include other hydrocarbons and alcohols (including Brazilian alcohol fuel and those used in gasoline blending elsewhere), Canadian synthetic oil production, Venezuelan upgraded Orinoco extra-heavy oil and orimulsion, oil shales, South African coal-based and natural gas-based oil substitutes and methanebased blending components such as MTBE. Total supply of these products is estimated at around 1.4 mb/d in 2003. Refinery processing gains are also shown as a source of oil supply in Table 1. Care needs to be taken in reading the text and tables to distinguish between crude oil and total oil supply. Thus, in Tables 1 and 3, total oil supply is shown (excluding OPEC).

...it seems a pretty wide definition to me, but valid enough provided one is aware of it. It would tend to underestimate decline in a narrower definition of oil products since it includes products that would presumably increase in supply as narrower oil supply declines.

I would interpret the graph as you. Looks like most supply increases that could be brought online rapidly and are viable at prices of $50 has been, unless ulterior motives have precluded it.

Perhaps that simplifies the supply prediction problem to:
new projects + infill additions + future recovery improvements - currently producing field declines

Seems that any existing production capacity which can (and there is the will to) be brought online, already has been. Of the above variables I think the field decline rates will be most critical and it looks like they are more likely to surprise to the bad side given what we know of Cantarell, Burgan, and might suspect of Ghawar.

Maybe the biggest fear should be that enhanced recovery techniques result in continued high levels of production in the short term followed by sharp decline rates, as in the Texas fields.

Interesting how the graphs, when scaled this way, appear to have slowing growth rates and currently appear to be rounding off.  The situation reminds me of a stock price technical top.  
Probably the same thing could have been said in 2002, based on this graph.

I'm skeptical of the IEA forcasts for the many reasons cited here, but it's good to be skeptical of those calling the peak as well.

In order to give some context, I "zoomed out" the IEA data by adding BP estimates (don't include all liquids):

It seems that the same kind of "event" happened in 2000 and 1999.

One of the reasons that we have a "zoom out" of data from 1950-2025 is to illustrates that this industry, like many, reflects politics and business cycles.  Natural gas and pork bellies are similar as supply and demand forcings react to weather and outside influence.

In our analysis we found that annual extraction has gone negative 9 times in the last 30 years.  

In short, a leveling or drop in production in 2006, considering all the factors in play at the moment mean zilch.  All the conservation and replacement efforts contemplated won't outpace the new demand from China and India and other developing regions.  A new middle class is emerging and their demand is insatiable.

Peaksters can get excited all they want watching the mid 2005 plateau and read into it what they want but the rest of us know it was hurricane and refinery related and the trendline will continue into 2010 amid the gnashing of teeth.

Neither you nor the Peak Oilers "know" anything. We can just look at pathetically inaedequate data and draw our best assumptions. The only thing we know for sure is that as Simmons says, we'll know it after the fact, not before.
Freddy - I'm glad you're with us at least that there is indeed something of a plateau that needs explaining.  Let's think about it from a different angle.  We know the IOCs, taken together, have been unable to increase production for a number of years.  All through that big 2002-2004 rise in global production, the IOCs were not contributing a whit to the cause.  They bought a lot of production on stream, but it just offset their decline rates.  Judging by the nice Bloomberg story we saw Dave post, we shouldn't expect much change in that in the next few years (as megaproject analysis tends to confirm).  So if production is to increase by a lot over the next 5-10 years, you've basically got two places with the reserves (maybe) to do it: Russia and Saudi Arabia.  Some people would argue even they can't increase production, but I tend to the view that they could if they really pulled all the stops out to do so.  As HO has been documenting at length in his posts, there's not much evidence that Saudi Arabia is drilling at the rate required for massive increases in production, and John Grace makes, to me, persuasive arguments in his book that Russian production is unlikely to increase too much more absent a large independent oil sector to go after all the smaller fields.  So they could increase production somewhat further, but for some reason they aren't acting like they plan to.  Why not?

Well, Putin and Abdullah basically control the price of oil.  How much should they charge?  Should they sell it cheap, such that demand will grow fast?  Or should they sell it dear so that demand will grow slowly?  Or very high so demand will collapse?  What's in their best interest?  They're not interested in maximizing global growth in oil production, they're interested in maximizing revenues to their respective regimes.  I would say that it's in their interest to charge as much as the market will bear without causing a substantial collapse in demand.  I suggest that would be high enough that any uses of oil with much elasticity will tend to get weeded out to make room for the growth in BRIC vehicle miles traveled.  There's a lot of inefficiencies in oil use such that it's quite possible for demand to go flat for a number of years as developing countries fuel-switch to coal for power generation and the vehicle fleet gets more efficient.  So if it's possible for demand to go flat, and it's in the self interest of the people who control the market for that to happen, why is it not going to happen?

I don't agree at all that Russian and SA distributers are manipulating prices.  In the good ole days sure.  They could crank up production (or cut back) in significant magnitudes.  But since 2003, their 3-5% changes mean nothing in a marketplace that sees monthly swings of up to 20%.  This is a market of fear and speculation and is verified by the recent record 2-mbd attributed to stock building over the last two quarters. Previously we saw 0.1 to 0.3-mbd adjustments to stocks each month.  Now we see positions forfeited 'cuz they don't want delivery and its sopped up by reserve growth in the end.  It is ludicrous in light of the obscene quarterly profits announced in 2005 to believe that the present price structure is cost driven.

Stuart, great graph work and i appreciate your insightful thoughts and questions each week.  Though we may not agree on everything, your objective presentations are superb, as is your reporting on conferences.  I treasure most of your posts.

SA and Russia are not manipulating prices.  They do have, however, the power to manipulate supply, and hence prices as  secondary effect.  Clearly Saudi Arabia has done this in the past - ususally by swamping the market with oil to drive down price.

As price is set on the open market by the marginal barrel, and demand for oil is relatively inelastic, at least in the short term, a small increase in supply has the potential to drive prices down precipitously. On the other side of the coin, disruptions in supply of one million barrels per day (Katrina for instance) cause significant price hikes in the other direction.

I agree with Stuart that SA and Russia are driven by self interest here.  I do not think in either case it is as simple as trying to maximize cash flow for their respective countries, however.

The rulers of SA can only maintain their power through controlling the oil production and keeping the $'s flowing through the econonomy.  Also they have made a "bargain with the devil", effectively trading access to oil for protection by the US military.  So SA needs to balance maximizing cash flow to the Kingdom without pissing off their protectors - the US Government.

Russia on the other hand is more complex.  Putin's power does not flow from the oil industry in his country.  In fact, he clearly felt that some of those guys, especially Kodorovsky in particular and Yukos in general, were a threat to his power.  I don't think Putin would blink an eye at shutting in 1 million barrels a day from Russia if he felt that it would improve his grip on power.

I have heard for two years now that the price of oil is being priced irrationally in the market and that there is a large "fear" premium in the price of oil.  If anything, in hindsight the market has acted exactly as it should have.  Demand has soared in the last couple of years without any obvious new supply sources coming on stream to cover this demand.  Excess supply capacity has been sopped up - especially for light sweet crude.  Without extra under-utilized supply capacity the price had to go up as demand soared.  Now that demand appears to have stopped its dramatic increase, the price for oil seems to have stabilized at between $52 and $62 per barrel.  Perhaps that in the coming year, with futher recovery from Katrina and Rita, some new projects coming on stream (Bonga and Thunderhorse for example) and a possible downturn in the world wide economy, it is possible to see oil drop back to $35/bbl.  However, if that happens I predict it will be short lived.

I'm not necessarily arguing that Russia and SA have been behind the big price increase of the last few years.  On the contrary, they've been the main sources of additional supply.  What I'm arguing is that between those two countries, they pretty much control whether oil supply can go up by much more or not in the future, and it's not in their interests to have it go up a lot more.  Any time you have a market where only two suppliers can decide if supply increases or not, you have a market where price is likely to be high.  I agree with you that SA in particular has to keep the US sweet enough.  I see the last couple of years of Saudi communications as a (fairly brilliantly executed) PR strategy to get the world used to high price without blaming them.  This is not to discount the issues of depletion in SA - just to note that there are significant reserves still, and they are taking a very measured pace to developing them.  I think this is a good thing.
Freddy:  I agree speculation and hedge funds have a lot to do with recent price rises (a good thing in my view).  I'm more pointing out that in the future, production is not going to rise much unless SA and Russia make very vigorous efforts to do so.  There simply is nowhere else with that much potential.  They don't have a strong incentive to do it as far as I can see, and in the case of SA, we can see they are only making relatively modest percentage efforts to increase production (though it would be a lot of production by anyone else's standards).  Thanks for the kind words!
True, but we had slow-downs in demand at those times. That was when dot-com's crashed, the economy went south, and energy demand fell. Oil prices were also lower, less motivating for producers.  I'm not sure the same case can be made now. I can't imagine many producers holding back at 60 per barrel. Also, Int'l demand relative to US has increased.
Those events were demand side driven.  1998 was the Asian flu, and 2001-2002 was the end of the tech bubble.  What has happened in the last year is supply side driven - whether or not you think the problem is temporary, I don't think anyone can claim demand collapsed because of recession - instead supply was unable to go up further, which has put the price up and prevented demand from continuing to rise.
It is interesting that world demand and production follow each other pretty close:

You would think there would be a lag. Of course the US demand and production has been going in opposite directions.

Greg,
This is exactly what one would expect since production = demand +/- storage.  What would be more interesting are graphs of actual production versus capacity to produce.  I would expect such graphs to show actual production approaching production capacity.  Does anyone know of a source for such data?
THis is why OPEC had until recently maintained a 4 - 5 million barrell per day spare capacity. What you are seeing is promarily due to the ability of OPEC to flexibly change production in reponse to circumstances. That's why the line follows so closely despite major events such as the two Iraq wars, Venezuelan oil strike, etc. However, now that OPEC no longer has this cushion, we will see much more volatility.
The two lines will stay pretty close together.  If demand drops, someone will shut-in production, since it's cheaper to store the unwanted oil down in the ground than produce it and then build more tanks to put it in.  If supply is constrained, obviously the price will go up by however much is required to reduce demand to what can actually be produced.  Demand in these graphs is "demand at the then current price" (which of course could be "demand after the economy tanks" in the worst case).
I agree. Sorry about the typos, I was in a hurry. The lines do stay together for the reasons you mention, but I think the OPEC cushion has allowed a rather unrestricted growth in demand over the past few years, such that basic demand is always met, and demand destruction has never cut very deep. Supply has not seriously affected the economy. I think this might change since the supply cushion is so much less now.
The curve reminds me a lot of the years preceding the 1972 Texas Peak.  

Texas production in 1962:  2.5 mbd.  
Texas production in 1972:  3.5 mpd.
Texas production in 1982:  2.5 mbd.  

The years after 1972 saw the biggest drilling boom in Texas history, resulting in an increase in the number of producing wells of 14% (by 1982), which did nothing to reverse the post-1972 decline. Perversely enough, Texas actually showed decreasing producing wells as production increased from 1962 to 1972.  

I think what this showed is the tremendous importance of the big--billion barrel and larger--oil fields, and I think that this is why Hubbert Linearization works.  In truth, what we are probably plotting is primarily the production decline from the big fields.  

The Texas analogy completely contradicts Yergin's assertion that a swarm of smaller fields will allow us to maintain, or even grow, world production.   Our experience to date in the Lower 48 in general and the North Sea--which are both following the Hubbert/Deffeyes predicted decline path--further contradict Yergin's premise (who by the way was firmly, in November, 2004, predicted oil prices of $38 per barrel in November, 2005).

I think what this showed is the tremendous importance of the big--billion barrel and larger--oil fields, and I think that this is why Hubbert Linearization works.  In truth, what we are probably plotting is primarily the production decline from the big fields.  

The Texas analogy completely contradicts Yergin's assertion that a swarm of smaller fields will allow us to maintain, or even grow, world production.


I think you're right, I tried once to simulate the effect of the field size distribution and the discovery pattern on the total production curve. New discovery are mainly small fields (Category 6, prod < 0.1 mbpd) and there are only a few new megaprojects (Category 2, prod > 0.5 mbpd) per decades. I assumed the following discovery distribution pattern where discovery of small fields is slowly decreasing but we keep discovering the small amount of larger fields:

It leads to the following production curve (Monte Carlo simulation):

Even if production from small fields (Cat 6. and Cat. 5) is almost 60% of the total production, it's resulting only in a heavier production tail but the main peak is coming from the megaproject and giant fields.
You might want to make use of the 'width = "X%"' attribute that HTML allows in an img tag.
Sorry about that! I think the automatic scaling doesn't work because the second image is in a png format.
Why when supergiants ,giants wells are found , at least from my lay perspective, appears the smaller wells aren't immediately drilled; and allow discovery that can soften the decline? Thanks.
So how do past predictions by Deffeyes, Campbell, Skrebowski coinside with these stats?  I believe that Skrebowski only predicted 80.3 mbd for 2005, and the ASPO, even in the December newsletter only predicted 81.
I think with all the alternative liquid fuels that will start to come online (ethanol, fischer-tropsch, soy diesel, tar sands etc) it will be increasingly difficult to see the true 'peak' in pure oil. Gradually this discussion will morph into "Peak Liquid Energy" and somewhere along the line, someone will get their arms around the data that really matters: the NET amount of oil (or energy) left for society AFTER the energy needed to create energy (refining, corn-to-ethanol, distribution, replacing oil rigs lost in hurricane, etc) is subtracted out from the 85mbpd. This is tough analysis, but post peak the EROI methodology will be central both to energy and financial decisions.

When we discuss "Peak Oil" in my opinion, it is the X - Y = Z that is really relevant. (X=oil supply, Y=energy cost of producing X, Z=oil left for non-energy production usages). When Z peaks is when the proverbial substance starts to hit the fan. Note: Z should peak before X.

I think you've hit upon my concern to adding various liquids together.  If this is to be done, then they each need to be weighted in some manner to account for the different EROEI first.  
In particular, I wonder how much oil in the totals was actually used to produce the ethanol that is also in the totals.
Good point.

I have been waiting for a COOP or some such to "close the loop" on the energy side.  This will be done when soybeans are pressed into soybean oil which is converted to biodiesel to put the next crop in.  Ditto for ethanol from some biomass, except that most tractors run on diesel.

The goal of this is to see what the net crop yield is 1-2 years into it.  Ignore fertilizers at the start.  You just want to see if you come out ahead when sunlight multiplies your grain yield each cycle.  Subtracting out that part of your crop that has to be turned back into liquid fuel.  If you don't get a net crop it's all a waste of time.  Never been done as far as I can determine.


Indeed this is true.

Consider for example a hypothetical process for converting electricity into liquid fuel.  The electricity is primarily generated from burning coal, so in effect what you have is an indirect CTL process of some sort (in light of this, I suppose one would simply compare against a F-T CTL process and see which is the most efficient).

Now consider ethanol.  People point at the EROEI of maybe 1.3 or so - not great really.  You do however need to consider what the actual energy inputs really are?  What fraction is actually oil, what fraction is natural gas, and what fraction of the energy inputs is electricity (which is somewhat more flexible in terms of energy inputs - theoretically even using wind).  In fact, some of the energy inputs are ultimately needed for heat (distillation) - one could also imagine that solar could easily be used to provide some of this heat.  

In light of this, I would argue that using EROEI as the only yardstick for measuring energy efficiency is really unwise.

what would you recommend, in its stead?
Those are my feelings exactly about EROEI.  It makes no explicit recognition of the types of fuels, and in particular, which are renewable, which are non-renewable but easily replaced by renewables, and which are non-renewable and not easily replaced.  (For "easily" read "in a short time frame and at acceptable cost.")

The EROEI viewpoint also ignores the fact that we live in an economic world in which adaptation and substitution is the norm.  EROEI, like the amount of oil in the ground, places an ultimate limit on certain types of activities, but in and of itself it says nothing about how we do things before we approach those limits.  And our behavior pre-peak (for oil, NG, or any other non-renewable resource) is just as critical as is the date of the peak and the decline rate post-peak.

I'm sure I'll get stoned for mentioning this, but there's always the example of flashlight batteries.  The energy expended to make one is many times the tiny amount it holds, yet we make them by the bargeload.  We're not stupid, we're just behaving in accordance with economics, including the current prices for resources and what people will pay for the finished product.  (And yes, I use rechargable batteries for almost everything.)  The core problem is that non-renewable resources are not priced as if they're precious, but according to production cost and/or what the market will bear.  

As I keep saying over and over: If we look at just part of the picture (just geology or economics, just oil or NG, just technology or public policy) we'll wildly misunderstand our evolving energy situation.  In my opinion, EROEI is certainly a valuable analytical tool, but it's by no means something that can be used in complete isolation from economic, market psychology, public policy, and technology considerations.

You have a good point.  Flashlight batteries are still useful because they are portable and standardized.  A standard energy interface may be beneficial even if there are losses in conversion, because it prevents a continual revision of infrastructure, and allows a common design of products that can be produced in higher volumes.  Standards are always like that - it is more important to have a standard than to have the best standard.  

I think this is the role electricity will have to play.  The problem is transportation, which has evolved to a different energy standard, and so the infrastructure will need to be largely replaced, at least eventually.  If we could start now in a big way, and could do this over a period of time similar to the present lifetime of an automobile, I guess it would not be too disruptive.  I'm not counting on that though.  

It's true that electricity has an important role to play post peak, but I wouldn't count on the grid system surviving in its current form. Vast areas currently operate as a single AC system - one of the most complex manifestations of our complex society. Imagine a huge stone wheel being pulled up a bumpy incline (load) by cables attached to a large fleet of trucks of different sizes (generators). The wheel must keep moving up the hill at a constant speed (frequency). The larger trucks are in radio contact with a controller (dispatcher) at the top of the hill who can tell them when to speed up and slow down, but the smaller trucks are independent (non-dispatchable). Extra trucks must be driving up the incline at the same speed (spinning reserve), waiting to take the place of a truck which breaks down for any reason. Still more trucks are parked at the side of the road (contingency reserve) and can start up quickly if necessary.

Now imagine a future when we're short of some kinds of  truck fuel, all the larger trucks are getting old, the cables are fraying and there's not much money available for maintenance. It's much harder to pull the wheel up the hill with a larger fleet of smaller trucks, and harder still to keep the speed constant when the controller at the top of the hill can't communicate with the smallest trucks. If the wheel becomes much larger (demand goes up as people switch to electricity when other fuels run short or become expensive), the whole exercise becomes vastly more difficult. The wheel could easily stall.

Yes, I design products for the electric utility industry, and I'm aware of the issues regarding the grid.  It will need considerable investment to take on the additional load it's going to have to support.  Mostly we talk about the need for new sources, but it won't help without transmission & distribution infrastructure.  I don't see that investment happening yet either!  Just waiting for Adam Smith.....he'll be along now any day!

Nobody said that Adam Smith's invisible hand has a gentle touch.  It could come up and give us all a good dope slap or a punch in the gut.
Where I live, the government has just proposed spending $40 billion on nuclear power and $30 billion on wind turbines as 80% of current generation capacity will reach the end of its design life within 15 years. All coal-fired generation is meant to be closed or converted to natural gas(!) by 2009. They're proposing a significant shift away from the current generation mix and could create problems with load following and frequency management. There's no mention of upgrades in transmission or distribution, and power prices are to be kept well below the spot market price so that consumption is subsidized. Smart meters will introduce time-of-day pricing, but the proposed differential is probably not high enough to lead to much load shifting. In my opinion, this programme is a recipe for disaster.

Personally, I'd be amazed if they could even fund their programme as the electricity supply industry is already so heavily indebted (to the tune of about $40 billion). Closing the coal plants would be political suicide as supply is already insufficient to meet peak demand without imports. The market operator came very close to declaring a power emergency (rolling blackouts)several times this past summer. I try to imagine this system coping with a shift toward increasing electricity demand for winter heating as natural gas becomes expensive or unavailable. I try to imagine it somehow absorbing demand for transportation, but it doesn't seem very realistic. Unless economic collapse drastically reduces demand, the power system is already in trouble.

Short DC links can get over the synchronisation problem. One is used to allow the export of spare French nuclear generated electricity to the UK. It is capable of operating in the other direction but rarely does. In this case the DC also eliminates the problems caused to undersea AC systems by the large capacitance but there are DC links of only a few metres used solely to eliminate the synchronisation problems.
I remember the French interconnector powering London and the south-east. Although expensive, back-to-back HVDC links make sense as far as I'm concerned. Personally I'd break up a lot of the larger AC systems in order to prevent disturbances from potentially propagating across the whole system. As the grid becomes increasingly stressed post peak (if power flows increase as regions experiencing shortages attempt to import more power for instance), a large AC system becomes increasingly vulnerable to problems emanating from its weakest areas.

In North America, Texas and Quebec currently operate as islands with HVDC connections, but the rest of the continent is covered by two huge AC grids. As we discovered on August 14th 2003, very large areas can be affected extremely rapidly by cascading system failure, and it can then be problematic getting the system restarted. For instance, in Ontario the nuclear fleet had gone into full shutdown (reactors poisoned) when the control rooms lost power. It took a week for them to return to full power, with the government begging the public to conserve in order to avoid rolling blackouts. If it had been winter there would have been serious problems.

Cascading system failure is likely when the margins are small. It should then not matter much if the interconnects are AC or DC when the grid is so strained that they can not be allowed to fail. (Not entirely correct, modern DC links can provide large ammounts of reactive power wich helps with system stability but that only moves the limit, there is still such a limit. )

What you do need is margins in spinning reserve and transmission lines or a control system that can break up a failing grid in viable parts where production and consumption match. Investing in such a control system is always a good idea since it helps with manny kinds of realiability problems.

The hardest part is that you can probably not motivate full scale tests of it, it would be as breaking fingers to prepare for an eventual accident breaking a leg. I use to joke that if we were more religious it would be a good idea to tear down the grid yearly on good friday(???) and resurrect it to the next day. :-)

And here we are cutting costs to keep the share price up.  Longer tree trimming cycles, less maintenance, pushing things closer to the edge.  You see, it's "better" now, there is less waste and we have optimized the industry so that it can make money.  What could be more important?  OK, sarcasm off.
I agree and it's very frustrating. Liberalisation of power systems has pushed many things to the edge. Spare capacity (for generation and transmission) is out because it was inefficient. Power wheeling lets you share reserve, but can strain a grid that hasn't seen enough investment. A sudden increase in demand for power or for power transmission (caused by switching from natural gas to electricity perhaps?) could cause serious problems for a system stretched to the limit. I think it was Kunstler who said efficiency was the straightest path to hell and I'm inclined to agree with him.

From the standpoint of the shareholders of the electric companies, these things all make a form of sense.  The problem is that other than the power not sold, there is no financial cost to the power company when there is a power outage.  All of the homes and restaurants that have to discard food, for example.  Businesses that cannot open.  Etc, etc.  The power companies never see these costs, of course.

In my area (and from what I gather this is nationwide) when the power goes out, typically hospitals, and police are the first to get it back, and this all seems entirely proper to me.  Then again, after Katrina the office of the VP called down to get restoration of power to the pipelines bumped above hospitals.

Some people argue that the lines should be buried, but that is far more expensive, and the power companies would never go ahead and do this sort of thing just for the fun of ut.

With some services (thinking internet here), a business rate essentially comes with guarantees of service.  A homeowner will be brought back online whenever they happen to get around to it - if you are trying to run a business at home using residential cable modem service, and the line goes down, the answer is "so sad, too bad".

I suppose from a business perspective, the power companies could offer a business rate which would come with a guarantee of higher priority of restoration when the power goes down, but businesses would probably not be terribly keen to pay even more for their power.

The deregulation and free market for power production in Sweden led to several good and bad things.

Small often rural power distributors was bought by by bigger companies and their staff reduced. This destroid the local knowledge needed to quickly service powerlines of low and medium quality. After a few years of general complaints most power distributors started to cablifie the 400V to about 40 kV network or install insulated cables on powerpoles. This was about a 20 year chedule project. Almost exactly a year ago we had a storm of near hurricane strengt, the wors for at least 30 years. About a 1/4 million withouth power and most of europes spare part inventory were emptied within a month. This led to the power companies promising a 10 year cablification and a little to hars laws demanding it do be done in about 5 years. A lot of the power production porfits is financing this massive cablification but it might force some of the smaller and well run power distributors into bankruptcy. Overall it is a trade off between lots of local service personell and more damage resistant technology.

The free market for trading power www.nordpool.com meant that a lot of power trading companies were started, some with their own production. But the market in Sweden has consolidated into three giant companies and few samll ones. The market is open between Norway, Denmark, Finland ans Sweden and the trading areas with different prises are segmented acoring to the grid bottlenecks. Manny of the small traders went bankrupt during price surges in winter with little hydropower available due to little rain. They had to buy high and sell low. There is yet no day to da or hour to hour prising for small customers, only for producers, trading companies and large customers.
The cost for producing power has become lower.

One problem has been the about 3 GW of old oil fired condensing powerplants left over from before the nuclear buildup that were used during extreme winter peaks. This ment between 0 and perhaps 200h duty per year and catastrophical economy so they were mothballed. To solve that problem a tariff on power transmission in the manin powerlines were instututed and it was used to pay for 2 GW of spare capacity for anyone to bid of selling. 2 GW i sto little but its is better then nothing. The reserve is old condensing powerplants, old gas turbines, some new gas turbines and continiously running indstries that can shut down with a few h notice. This is said to be a temporary solution but I guess it will be permanent since it isent that expensive compared to the market turnaround and it is hard to figure out how to create a market that fullfills the need.

Electricity prices are overall going up, due to more consumption and exchange with mostly germany where the prise levels are higher. The "green" power subsidies has been replaced by a law forcing people to buy a small percentage of "green" power to finance building of wind powerplants and so on. The european carbon trading certificats and carbon emission quotas have had an immense economical effect, about 5 times bigger then anticipated. This has affected the whole price level turning old hydro powerplants and nuclear powerplants into gold mines and are strongly encouraging investments in combined powerplants and wind power.

But prices are si high now that it is starting to scare away some industry. A Finnish consortioum of heavy industry are the main financers of their fifth nuclear powerplant that should go on line with about 1600 MW in a few years. A Swedish consortium of heavy industry has recently finalized a gigadollar deal of electricity import from Russia to the nordic market and is building a GW HVDC line for it.
2 x 600 MW of swedish nuclear power has been mothballed, perhaps for ever by the greens but on the other hand the 10  hand the 10 reactors left are being life extended and upgraded with with the same total capacity.

The nordic countris has a cooperation on the running of the high voltage grid where they set the capacity goals needed for the stability and power trading. This has led to a number of strengthening projects and the politica will was bigger after a breakdown in southern sweden a few years ago when the grid had a freak n-3 failure that would have been survided with another powerline or if any of the closed nuclear reactors had been running.

The high load limit is one n-1 failure folowed by another one 15 min or more later to allow startup of new running reserve. This goal is right now not fulfilled for a 10% coldest winter if any powerplant is of line. :-(

I think our deregulation so far has done more good then bad things. But the anti nuclear politicians have muddled it, some of the political manipulation is clumsy, some of it is not as free as it should be and other parts dont work well as a free market right now. And to make things complicated the electricity taxes have been raised significantly, mostly for fiscal reasons.

I fumbled the preview, please someone kill this version.
The deregulation and free market for power production in Sweden led to several good and bad things.

Small often rural power distributors were bought by by bigger companies and their staff reduced. This led to a loss of local knowledge needed to quickly service powerlines of low and medium quality. After a few years of general complaints most power distributors started to cablifie the 400V to about 40 kV network or install insulated cables on powerpoles. This was often planned as a 20 year chedule project. Almost exactly a year ago we had a storm of near hurricane strengt, the worst for at least 30 years. About a 1/4 million withouth power and most of europes spare part inventory were emptied within a month. This led to the power companies promising a 10 year cablification. And a little to harsh laws demanding it do be done in about 5 years were written. A lot of the power production profits are financing this massive cablification but it might force some of the smaller and well run power distributors into bankruptcy. Overall it is a trade off between lots of local service personell and more damage resistant technology.

The free market for trading power www.nordpool.com meant that a lot of power trading companies were started, some with their own production. But the market in Sweden has consolidated into three giant companies and a few small ones. The market is open between Norway, Denmark, Finland ans Sweden and the trading areas with different prises are segmented acoring to the grid bottlenecks. Manny of the small traders went bankrupt during price surges in winter with little hydropower available due to little rain. They had to buy high and sell low. There is yet no day to da or hour to hour prising for small customers, only for producers, trading companies and large customers.
The cost for producing power has become lower.

One problem has been the about 3 GW of old oil fired condensing powerplants left over from before the nuclear buildup that were used during extreme winter peaks. This gave between 0 and perhaps 200h duty per year and catastrophical economy so they were closed or mothballed. To solve that problem a tariff on power transmission on the high tension powerlines were instituted and it was used to pay for 2 GW of spare capacity for anyone to bid of selling. 2 GW is too little but its is better then nothing. The reserve is old condensing powerplants, old gas turbines, some new gas turbines and continiously running indstries that can shut down with a few h notice. This is said to be a temporary solution but I guess it will be permanent since it isent that expensive compared to the market turnaround and it is hard to figure out how to quickly create a market that fullfills this need.

Electricity prices are overall going up, due to more consumption and exchange with mostly germany where the prise levels are higher. The "green" power subsidies has been replaced by a law forcing people to buy a small percentage of "green" power to finance building of wind powerplants and so on. The european carbon trading certificats and carbon emission quotas have had an immense economical effect, about 5 times bigger then anticipated. This has affected the whole price level turning old hydro powerplants and nuclear powerplants into gold mines and are strongly encouraging investments in combined powerplants and wind power.

But prices are so high now that it is starting to scare away some industry. A Finnish consortioum of heavy industries are the main financers of their fifth nuclear powerplant that should go on line with about 1600 MW in a few years. A Swedish consortium of heavy industries has recently finalized a gigadollar deal of electricity import from Russia to the nordic market and is building a GW HVDC line for it.
2 x 600 MW of swedish nuclear power have been mothballed, perhaps for ever by the greens but on the other hand the 10 reactors left are being life extended and upgraded with with the same total nuclear capacity.

The nordic countris has a cooperation on the running of the high voltage grid where they set the capacity goals needed for the stability and power trading. This has led to a number of powerline projects and the politica will were stimulated by a breakdown in southern sweden a few years ago when the grid had a freak n-2/n-3 failure that would have been survided with another powerline or if any of the closed nuclear reactors had been running. This led to a debate about the grids reliability but it will take a few years to build the additional high tension lines and HVDC links.

The design goal is to handle one n-1 failure folowed by another one 15 min or more later to allow startup of new running reserve in the form of spare hydro turbines and gas turbines. This goal is right now not fulfilled for a 10% coldest winter if any powerplant is of line. :-(
We risk rolling blackouts if we have a few realy cold winter days.

I think our deregulation so far has done more good then bad things. But the anti nuclear politicians have muddled it, some of the political manipulation is clumsy, some of it is not as free as it should be and other parts dont work well as a free market right now. And to make things complicated the electricity taxes have been raised significantly, mostly for fiscal reasons. This has made the deregulation very unpopular.

Lou,
This is an issue that deserves much clarification.  The price of any energy source is a combination of the actual energy provided by that source +/- a whole host of quality factors such as portability, size, density, etc.  As such EROEI by itself is only a first order estimate of the price when energy prices are high.  It should not be taken too far since, as energy is transformed into various useful forms, the EROEI ratio eventually drops to zero.  The EROEI concept is most useful when the energy input is of the same or similar quality to the energy output.  It tells you that if the cost of your input is dominated by energy, then (to a first order approximation) for a process to be worthwhile, the energy output must be greater.  This should be obvious to everyone but detractors of its use have tended to assume that the concept is meant to be some energy theory of value.
Speaking as one of the economists around this joint, I would say that the energy content is only vaguely related to the price, at best.  What matters is perceived utility of the good or service, how it competes with substitutes, and how the price might be manipulated by non-market forces.
...I would say that the energy content is only vaguely related to the price...

True when energy costs are low relative to the total delivered but not when energy costs are high.  For example, in California, typically 30% of residential bills is the cost of wholesale energy.  During the energy crisis that figure rose to about 70% at the margin.

I agree that the data will become (even) more muddled, and that net energy available (Z) is the final determining factor for how well we do.

But let's add in one more complexity: the issue of substitutability. We don't have an infinite range of choices about how to use our liquids. A given barrel of oil will produce various amounts of gasoline, diesel, kerosene, asphalt, and so on--but most can't be easily substituted for one another. Sometimes the substitutes work in one direction. We can pretty easily substitite ethanol for gasoline (10% as gasohol, 85% as E85), but I doubt the reverse is true.

This has the effect of adding in another huge, difficult management problem. We will probably have critical shortages of the most sought-after products, but less pressure on the less-wanted products. We see this at the broad level with oversupply of OPEC heavy sour crude, and tightness in lighter grades like WTI or Brent.

So I agree, having enough Z net energy is the minimum--it's a necessary condition, but not wholly sufficient. We also have to have enough Z in a form we can (or will) use it. Which won't make it any easier--

If X = total amount of global energy, Y=total energy used to produce X and Z is the difference left over for society, it would be instructive to graph the shape of X vs Y over time. Of course X can never equal Y or else Jay Hansons motor scooter example becomes true.

What % of X is Y? What % of X is for food? What % of X is for military? What % of X could be construed negative environmental externality,etc?  Is the rate of change in Y/X increasing? Someone needs to attempt to do this. (Staniford is 8/5 favorite). As long as Z is increasing, no one will bother asking whether it makes sense to make/buy batteries. Once Z starts to decline, there will be a rush to buy all batteries in sight (and windmills, and solar panels, etc).

Thanks for the hard work Stuart, but... weren't we talking about Regular in Thanksgiving?

Freddy has been talking about 'all liquids', which is becoming a gloomier thing every day - now even ethanol counts. Still 84 - 85 MBD is the top interval given by people like Boone Pickens.

Let's just wait for OGC 4Q stats. As for 'all liquids' I prefer BP's data.

Exxon, BP Rebuff Pleas to Boost Exploration as Oil Demand Soars (Bloomberg, today) Highly recommended. There's too much material to cover here. Some highlights.

Soaring Demand
After starving their exploration divisions, oil companies were incapable of quickly increasing supplies when demand unexpectedly started to soar in 2000, says Ken Chew, who analyzes data at IHS Energy, an industry consulting firm in Englewood, Colorado. The boom in emerging-market economies has spurred the increased consumption of gasoline and diesel and jet fuels.

In 2005, the Middle East accounted for almost a quarter of this worldwide gain. China, whose industrializing economy expanded 9.4 percent in the third quarter, was the second- largest source of demand growth, followed by the U.S., which burns one-fourth of the world's crude oil.

The combination of surging demand and anemic supplies has pushed oil prices up about 20 percent a year since 2000. Prices touched a record $70.85 a barrel in August 2005 following Hurricane Katrina's U.S. landfall, more than triple the average of $19.69 in the 1990s.
[IOC] spending shortfalls, falling discoveries...
ConocoPhillips CEO James Mulva says his company is spending as much as it can on searching for oil and developing new wells. Mulva, 58, says investment is being constrained after 147 years of exploration as companies struggle to find deposits large enough to produce sufficient profits. In the past four years, the average discovery outside of North America was the equivalent of 38.6 million barrels. That's less than half the amount of oil burned every day around the world and the lowest average for a four-year period since 1901, Chew says.

``We're finding less and less,'' he says. ``The resource is still huge; it's just that much of that is either in the Arctic or places like Iraq.''
Where's the oil? Costs skyrocketing....
The biggest deposits are in remote locations or buried very deep in the ground, driving up costs to record levels. ``New developments are occurring but in challenging and capital- intensive locations, such as the deep water, the Arctic and oil sands in Canada,'' Chevron CEO David O'Reilly, 59, told the Senate panel, made up of the Energy and Natural Resources and Commerce, Science and Transportation committees....

A Shell-led group built the Molikpaq platform off the coast of Russia's Far East to exploit reserves beneath the sea floor. The platform, which began operating in 1999, can pump oil only during the warmest months of the year because large blocks of ice make the sea impassable for tanker ships for half of the year. The cost of finding and pumping a barrel of oil reached an all-time high of $17.12 in 2004, up 43 percent from a year earlier, according to Bloomberg data.

``Costs are climbing at a speed you can't even imagine,'' says Christophe de Margerie, Total's head of exploration and production.
Reading this article, the apparent supply inflection in 2005 is no surprise at all regardless of how many liquids the IEA throws into the mix.
I wonder if the 'oil' produced by Sasol (from coal)is already included in the total barrels per day for the world.
Yes, at least in the EIA numbers.  Check out the reference Agric quoted above.
If you look at   http://www.eia.doe.gov/emeu/ipsr/t14.xls , which is Table 1.4 World Oil Supply, 1997-Present (Thousand Barrels per Day) you get September production of 83,227 as against May at 84,652. (The reason September is down is that Katrina cut nearly 1,500 off US production - Rita wouldn't show up yet). This includes Natural gas Liquids, I believe.

I think that the decline in many fields is such that, by the time the Gulf returns to previous levels, the rest of the world will be down further and May 2005 looks, to me, to be some kind of peak.

The green line in the graph at the start of the article is exactly from that table.  Freddy's point yesterday was the the IEA line, which goes a couple of months further than the EIA line, turns up again, and goes higher in November (though not very much higher).
We won't have reliable Nov numbers till February.
I admit to being surprised at how well the oil situation has gone in light of the hurricanes. The "peakers" like Campbell do have a record of being to quick to call the peak, but the oil companies, conventional oil analysts, and national oil companies have an equally bad record of overestimating production, underestimating impact of depletion/decline and putting the peak too for off in every region that has peaked so far.

Maybe some happy medium.

What I see in the Graph is a shrinking of the annual variations in production. The peaks and troughs get closer to each other every year. Could this be a sign of The Peak?
The graph is linear. If it were log, the recent peak/troughs would look even smaller compared with earlier ones. But, this does not necessarily imply peak - when OPEC had spare capacity they probably pumped more during peak demand periods, less when price was lower. The lack of variation simply shows that everybody is pumping full bore all year round, not whether new fields will or will not increase production in the future.
More curious is why August was not the peak to date, that is, just before the gom went down.
Stuart, I do not think hedge funds are responsible for the price increase. At the recently hit price of $56 a barrel there were a record number fo short positions, perhaps appropriate as we had our highest oil usage week ever just a couple of weeks after that. Heating oil showed similiar stats. If all that shorting can get oil only down to $56 it shows things can get really bad if hedge funds go long.